Theory of Hegemonic War
“The great turning points in world history have been provided by these hegemonic struggles among political rivals; these periodic conflicts have reordered the international system and propelled history in new and unchartered directions. They resolve the question of which state will govern the system, as well as what ideas and values will predominate, thereby determining the ethos of successive ages.”
“The fundamental problem of international relations in the contemporary world is the problem of peaceful adjustment to the consequences of the uneven growth of power among states, just as it was in the past. International society cannot and does not stand still. War and violence remain serious possibilities as the world moves from the decay of one international system toward the creation of another.”
Robert Gilpin, War & Change in World Politics
In a contemplative article, William C. Wohlforth wondered what contemporary political science would’ve looked like if instead of Waltz’ neorealism, Gilpin’s formulation had become the central organizing theory of the discipline. Gilpin’s framework – laid out in War & Change in World Politics – is considerably more nuanced than the monocausal, static, systemic formulation of great power politics in neorealism.[1] Often conflated with Organski’s theory of power transition, it is referred to as hegemonic stability theory. Gilpin focuses on how the international order emerges from hegemonic wars, is forged and upheld by dominant states, and how it comes under pressure from rising powers.
Hegemonic wars
According to Gilpin, a hegemonic war is characterized by three features. First, it is a system-wide conflict: every great power and most minor powers participate in the war. Second, it’s a total war: what is at stake is the nature and governance of the international order. It is at once political, economic, and ideological; is characterized by the employment of unlimited means, and usually accompanied by religious, political, and social upheaval. That is, it is simultaneously a systemic crisis. Third, the geographic scope expands till it engulfs the entire system: it is a world war.
Historically, the wars that meet these three criteria are: the Peloponnesian war between Athens and Sparta (431-404 B.C.), the Second Punic war between Carthage and Rome (218-201 B.C.), the Thirty Years War (1618-48), the wars of Louis XIV (1667-1713), the wars of the French revolution and Napoleon (1792-1814), the First World War (1914-19), and the Second World War (1939-45).
A number of preconditions are associated with the outbreak of hegemonic war. There is a “closing in” of the system whereby interstate relations become more and more a zero-sum game. The clashes among great powers over territory, resources, and markets increase in frequency and magnitude. In contrast, the hundred years of peace of the long nineteenth century was based on “continuously expanding territories and markets”.[2] Another precondition is a significant erosion in the relative power of the reigning hegemon. The dominant state sees that time is working against it and feels that one should settle matters through preemptive war while the advantage is still on one’s side.
Dale C. Copeland contends that in hegemonic stability theory it is the ascending power that is inclined to initiate war to receive the status and rewards denied by the traditional system.[3] This is Organski’s position and manifestly not Gilpin’s, as Copeland actually concedes in the appendix. Gilpin, in fact, devotes most of his attention to the dilemma of the declining power, of which he says: “The first and most attractive option is to eliminate the source of the problem. By launching a preventive war the declining power destroys or weakens the rising challenger while the military advantage is still with the declining power.” [Emphasis mine.] In what amounts to either pure fabrication or extremely shoddy scholarship, Copeland says that Gilpin puts most of the blame on the rising state and references pages 33, 94-95, and 186-187. Nowhere on these pages does Gilpin ever suggest that the rising power even contemplates initiating war. Throughout the book, Gilpin argues that the rising state or states seek to change the status quo. His position is considerably more nuanced and Copeland does a great disservice by misrepresenting it. Let me quote Gilpin at length:
Although prestige is largely a function of economic and military capabilities, it is achieved primarily through the successful use of power, and especially through victory in war. The most prestigious members of the international system are those states that have most recently used military force or economic power successfully and have thereby imposed their will on others. Second, both power and prestige are ultimately imponderable and incalculable; they cannot be known absolutely by any a priori process of calculation. They are known only when they are tested, especially on the field of battle. Third, one of the principal functions of war, particularly what we shall call hegemonic war, is to determine the international hierarchy of prestige and thereby determine which states will in effect govern the international system.
[A]n inconsistency may, and in time does, arise between the established hierarchy of prestige and the existing distribution of power among states. That is, perceptions of prestige lag behind changes in the actual capabilities of states. As a consequence, the governance of the system begins to break down as perceptions catch up with the realities of power. The once dominant state is decreasingly able to impose its will on others and/or protect its interests. The rising state or states in the system increasingly demand changes in the system that will reflect their newly gained power and their unmet interests. Finally, the stalemate and issue of who will run the system are resolved through armed conflict.
Unable to tackle the nuance of Gilpin’s framework, Copeland erects a straw man: “hegemonic stability theory has no deductively consistent theory of war initiation. There is no logical reason why a state should attack while it is still rising, since simply by waiting, the state will be able to achieve its objectives more easily and at less cost.” His account of the origins of the First World War thus casts Germany as the dominant state in decline. This does explain why Germany engineered the war when it did: Russia had much greater war potential due to its large population and territory. It was rapidly industrializing and had just started an arms buildup that would’ve enabled it to surpass Germany as the dominant military power on the continent by 1917.
However, Germany was in no way the dominant power in the international order. The reigning hegemon was Great Britain. Both authors agree on Britain’s response to relative decline. As Germany surpassed Great Britain in industrial strength, it launched on a naval buildup to challenge the Royal Navy for command of the seas. The Kaiser inaugurated a strategy of coercive diplomacy to extract concessions from the imperial powers. This strategy of calculated risk and brinksmanship called Weltpolitik alarmed Great Britain. She immediately started resolving her conflicts with other great powers and forging alliances: agreed to Japanese supremacy in northeast Asia, American dominance of the western hemisphere, gave over the western Mediterranean to France, and made diplomatic overtures to Russia.
The reason why Great Britain did not consider preventive war with Germany is clear. What counts in the balance of power is land-based military power. Germany had been a stronger military power than Great Britain since 1870. Even if she had been able to forge an alliance with France and Russia to attack Germany, they would’ve found it difficult to bring it down. The strategy of containment and encirclement that Britain pursued was thus optimal. Great Britain continued to preside over the international order.
The issue is a subtle one: a dominant military power in irreversible relative decline faced with a geopolitical rival with greater war potential will consider preventive war to be necessary if no other option is available to ensure its long-term survival. In a multi-polar system, their course of action would immediately make it a potential hegemon. The balance of power dynamic will kick in, all the other great powers would coalesce to check it, and it would have to make a run for the entire system. It would thus only launch a preventive war if it was at least as strong as its geopolitical rivals put together.
This was precisely Germany’s position before both the world wars. Since such a situation is harder to obtain in multi-polarity than bipolarity, the former is more stable than the latter. In the bipolar system on the other hand, even if the declining power is somewhat weaker than the rising power it would still make sense for it to launch a preventive war to shore up its waning long-term security. Thus, bipolar systems are inherently less stable. Here, the logic of Copeland’s theory of dynamic differentials is impeccable and superior to neorealism. Since neorealism is a static theory, it misses the central role that the law of uneven growth plays in precipitating war. Neorealism therefore sees bipolarity to be inherently more stable than multi-polarity.
Hegemons and the governance of the international order
The reigning hegemon has, with the exception of the United States, not been the dominant military power in the system. However, it has, by necessity, been the dominant naval power. Since the sixteenth century, when the European world economy spread its tentacles around the globe, the principal determinant of the financial and economic fortunes of the great powers have been their positions in the global trading system. Since every great power benefits in absolute terms from the global trading system, it endows the sea power that protects the sea-lanes with an enormous degree of power and prestige. They have, as a rule, promoted free trade, provided the investment capital, run the financial system, and supplied the international currency.
The key to controlling this maritime realm is sea power, which is quite distinct from land-based military power. Indeed, when we speak of war potential and dominant states, we are implicitly talking about the latter. The former is determined by factors that are quite distinct. Naval supremacy depends in the first instance on having a skilled merchant navy and ship building industry. It also depends quite critically on securing control over strategic control points, what Admiral Lord Fisher called “the five keys that lock up the world”: Gibraltar, Dovar, the Strait of Malacca, the Cape of Good Hope, and Alexandria. To update this list we may add the Panama and Suez canals and the Strait of Hormuz. The sea power that controls these is more often than not the reigning hegemon of the world economy.
Since the trade between East Asia and Europe has been such a crucial piece of the global trading jigsaw, naval control of the Strait of Malacca serves as the truest bellwether of established hegemonies: Iberian (Portuguese) (1511-1640), Dutch (1640-1780), British (1780-1945), and American (1945-).
All hegemonic wars in history were initiated by dominant military powers who were not only facing relative decline (as Copeland demonstrates admirably) but also fighting against the secular trend of the world economy. Sparta was threatened by the maritime trading empire of Athens. Carthage, the hitherto dominant sea power feared Rome’s growing strength at sea: the Punic wars were precipitated by Rome’s conquest of strategically significant islands in the Mediterranean, which posed a direct threat to Carthage’s naval supremacy and trade primacy. Spain tried in vain to prevent Holland’s rise to primacy in global trade and finance. The wars of Louis XIV were as much about wrestling Dutch trade as establishing France as the dominant power in Europe. The Napoleonic wars were intended to reverse Britain’s rise as the dominant trading and maritime power. Napoleon was, however, a few decades late to the party. Germany tried twice in a generation to secure the mantle of the world economy and the international order even as it was silently crossing the Atlantic.
The lessons to be gleaned from this exercise are manifold. The balance of power and the maritime world economy are distinct. The principal determinant of a great power’s position in the former is land-based military power, while in the latter it is sea power and economic prowess. War potential is determined by territory, population, advantageous geopolitical location, and resource endowment (Iron, coal, oil et cetera). Successful maritime powers need to be economic powerhouses, have a highly skilled and productive populace, and substantial naval potential (ample coastline, shipbuilding, a sea-faring tradition et cetera). Perhaps most importantly, they need to be incubators of capitalism.
Coming back to the German tragedy, there was virtually no possibility of German hegemony of the sort enjoyed by the Americans. Even if the Schlieffen plan had been implement in 1905 and Germany had become preponderant in Europe, it would’ve only enjoyed a slight advantage over the American colossus. The geopolitical advantages of the United States – primarily the security provided by the Atlantic and the Pacific oceans – meant that it was a foregone conclusion that the US would’ve emerged as a pole of the international system. The emergent world order in this hypothetical scenario would’ve been tripolar with the US, Germany and Japan preponderant in their respective spheres. This has, in fact, been the shape of the international economic system for the past half century. As indeed, it would’ve been for the past hundred years if we had been spared the devastations of the early twentieth century. These are topological invariants of the world economy.
The polarity of the international security system is given by the distribution of military power. The polarity of the world economy is a feature that is at once deeper and longer lasting than the military standing of states. Even though the modern state has enormous power, it is almost helpless in the face of the world economy. Witness the failure of the strongest state in human history to bring the unemployment rate down half a percentage point.
Do nuclear weapons make hegemonic wars anachronistic?
It has been argued that nuclear weapons make hegemonic wars extremely unlikely. This is a misunderstanding of what nuclear weapons can and cannot do. Even a medium sized power with a credible second strike capability can be assured of not being conquered outright. Nuclear weapons therefore provide a basic quantum of security to their possessors. However, what nuclear weapons cannot do is protect the power position of a state. Kissinger pointed out that “under conditions of mutual deterrence, a series of limited wars could serve to change the international system.”[4] For instance, the US will not risk nuclear annihilation if China were to muscle it out of the Persian Gulf or wrestle away control of the Strait of Malacca. This is what is known as bologna tactics. Indeed, the effect of nuclear weapons on hegemonic struggles will be quite the opposite: by making total war unthinkable, nuclear weapons “serve ultimately to inhibit the dominant power from defending the status quo rather than preventing the rising power from seeking to change it.”
With the development of missile defense shields and reliable intelligence gathering capabilities, it might be possible for a great power to achieve nuclear superiority. Indeed, it has been argued that the United States has already acquired nuclear primacy.[5] But this is not exactly a return to the nuclear monopoly of 1945-49. Since a small probability that a usable warhead might survive cannot be eliminated even with a substantial surprise first strike, nuclear weapons continue to protect weaker powers against nuclear blackmail by the dominant superpower. Indeed, Kenneth Waltz has argued that a nuclear Iran would stabilize the regional order in the Middle East by eliminating the threat of US-Israeli conquest of the beleaguered Islamic republic.[6]
The coming hegemonic war
The global security order is unipolar. This does not mean that the United States can get its way on every issue. It does mean that if a vital interest of the US is at stake, no other state or group of states can check the exercise of US power. US primacy basically means that “no major power is in a position to follow any policy that depends for its success on prevailing against the United States in a war or an extended rivalry.”[7]
The world economy is centered. New York serves as the “organizing center” of global capitalism. If one looks at the network of global corporate control, in particular, the strongly connected component or core of the system, one finds the stark fact that the top 1,318 companies control 80 per cent of global revenues of 43,060 transnational corporations. Atop this tightly-knit control structure are 147 firms that control 40 per cent of the world’s corporate revenue. This is “ten times bigger than what could be expected based on their wealth”. Note also that wealth is already much more skewed than income. An analysis of the control shares of the top fifty firms provided by the authors reveals that the share of US firms in this supercore is an astounding 54.5 per cent, that of other western firms is 40.6 per cent, and that of Japanese firms is 4.1 per cent. The state owned Chinese oil company controls 0.8 per cent. The reins of the world economy are held pretty tightly.
The world economy is tripolar. Leadership in an open global economy depends on a country’s market share of the most profitable sectors. These are overwhelming high-end services (financial services and consulting), and especially high-tech manufacturing. The growth in manufacturing productivity is the principal determinant of the health of an advanced industrial economy. The countries with the highest productivity in high-tech manufacturing invariably capture the largest share of the pie. It is here that we find three highly competitive zones in the world economy: United States, a German dominated northern European core, and the northeast-Asian core centered at Japan that includes Taiwan, South Korea, and Hong Kong. These are the only major centers of independent technological development and innovation. The rapidly growing countries outside this core are invariably importing advanced technologies from abroad. This includes China.
China surpassed the United States in manufacturing output in 2011. China’s manufacturing sector employs more than a hundred million people compared to ten million in the US. This does not mean that American workers are ten times as productive as Chinese workers. China’s manufacturing is labor intensive and characterized by low value-added per worker. On the other hand, US manufacturing is high-tech and capital intensive. They just make different things. This tells us more about the hierarchical structure of the global supply chains than relative productivity.
What all the above implies is that we are very far indeed from the next hegemonic war. However, the pace of change in the world economy is rapid. Chinese strategists reckon that they will be able to close the technological gap with the United States by mid-century. These projections are picked out of thin air of course. No one really knows how this plays out. China has very many hurdles to cross before it becomes a serious rival for the leadership of the world economy.
What we can say is that China has tremendous war potential. If China continues to grow rapidly and modernizes its military, China would be able to balance the US perhaps as early as 2025. The world would then become bipolar. A necessary condition of this first step towards superpower status would be for China to secure its energy supply by becoming militarily preponderant in Central Asia. If it continues to industrialize and grow for another decade or two it would emerge as a serious “peer competitor” to America. The United States will try in vain to shore up its power position, perhaps launching a cold war when it finds itself in relative decline. Initial moves towards such a scenario have already begun with the Obama administration’s initiative to “rebalance towards east Asia”. I think Copeland is right: it will be America that initiates a hawkish containment policy as soon as US policymakers are certain about relative decline.
Once serious decline sets in the US, the governance of the international system will become weak and ineffective. There will most certainly be a struggle for hegemony. Hopefully, it will be a series of localized wars and no nuclear weapons will be used. Once the Strait of Malacca comes under Chinese protection, everyone will know who the top dog is.
No dominant state in history has ever relinquished its power position without a fight and no rising hegemon has ever established itself as the dominant state in the international order without fighting and winning a hegemonic war. There is no reason to believe that we have somehow passed into post-history because of some ideational revolution in human consciousness. The rule of force in world affairs has not been transcended. The organizing principle of the international system is still anarchy. The international relations of states are still primarily characterized by power politics. The motor of history continues to operate. Let me end here with another quote from Gilpin:
“The conclusion of one hegemonic war is the beginning of another cycle of growth, expansion, and eventual decline. The law of uneven growth continues to redistribute power, thus undermining the status quo established by the last hegemonic struggle. It has always been thus and always will be, until men either destroy themselves or learn to develop an effective mechanism of peaceful change.”
[1] Gilpin, Robert. War and Change in World Politics. Cambridge: Cambridge UP, 1981. Print.
[2] Carr, E. H. The Twenty Years' Crisis: 1919-1939. London: MacMillan, 1942. Print.
[3] Copeland, Dale C. The Origins of Major War. Ithaca: Cornell UP, 2000. Print.
[4] Kissinger, Henry. A World Restored; Metternich, Castlereagh and the Problems of Peace, 1812-22. Boston: Houghton Mifflin, 1957. Print.
[5] Lieber, Keir A., and Daryl G. Press. "The Rise of U.S. Nuclear Primacy." Foreign Affairs. March 1, 2006.
[6] Waltz, Kenneth N. "Why Iran Should Get the Bomb." Foreign Affairs. June 15, 2012.
[7] Wohlforth, William C. "The Stability of a Unipolar World." International Security 24.1 (1999): 5-41. Print.